6 Vertical Integration WHAT IS CORPORATE STRATEGY? The six chapters in Part 3 of the book (Chapters 6-11) deal with corporate strategies. It is a good idea to take a step back and look at the definition of corporate strategy given in Chapter 1. Corporate (or corporate-level) strategies are actions firms take to gain competitive advantages by operating in multiple markets or industries simultaneously. Thus, they expand on business-level strategies, which focus on gaining competitive advantage in a single market or industry. The instructor can reiterate to students that corporate strategy deals with both the form (vertical integration, diversification) as well as the means (mergers and acquisitions and strategic alliances). Important Point: Corporate level strategy addresses the question: In which business(es) should the firm operate? Managers use corporate level strategy to help ensure that the corporation is composed of the optimal mix of businesses. Slide 6-2 This slide provides a good overview of this chapter by identifying its place in the strategic management process. Students should understand the logic of corporate-level strategy. As the class discussion transitions from the logic of business-level strategy to that of corporate-level strategy, it is important that they understand that the move is not just incremental—from managing one business to managing a set of businesses. Using Slide 6-3, the instructor should take students through the following key points: corporate-level strategy should create value for the organization: such that the value of the corporate whole increases such that businesses forming the corporate whole (i.e., the portfolio) are worth more than they would be under independent ownership that equity investors cannot create through portfolio investing (on their own) Owning a portfolio of businesses comes with a cost—the costs associated with running a bureaucracy. The benefits should outweigh the costs for corporate-level strategy to make sense. The benefits typically come in the form of synergies. In the case of vertical integration, the key benefit comes in the form of value chain economies. Value Chain Economies: Value chain economies are those economies that are created by integrating a market transaction into the boundaries of the firm. For example, a firm that buys one of its suppliers may realize an economy by coordinating the production of the supply with the needs of the parent firm. Slide 6-3 Use this slide to show students the logic of corporate level strategy in general, and vertical integration in particular. The slide can also be used to introduce students to the fact that vertical integration deals with value chain economies. It is important that students understand this logic because it will be referenced throughout the remainder of the course. WHAT IS VERTICAL INTEGRATION? Define Vertical Integration, Forward Vertical Integration, and Backward Vertical Integration Value chains were first introduced in Chapter 3. To help students get this point clearly, the instructor can say that the value chain (primary and support activities) of Chapter 3 can be thought of as the firm’s internal value chain, while the value chain in Figure 6.1 is the industry value chain. The pizza example in Slide 6.4 is a great one to use because the product is very familiar to students. After showing the slide, introduce students to Coase’s work on firm boundaries. Take students through various possibilities – a pizza chain getting into the business of food distribution (say, Domino’s Pizza acquiring a food service company such as Sysco) or a cheese producer (Leprino Foods) acquiring or starting a pizza chain. Slide 6-4 This slide uses the example of Leprino Foods, one of the largest producers of mozzarella cheese in the U.S., to help explain the concept of vertical integration. Once students understand the basic concept of vertical integration (increasing a firm’s boundaries to include multiple value chain activities), the instructor can continue with the pizza example to differentiate between backward and forward integration. Using Leprino Foods as the focal firm, point out that backward integration is going back in the value chain (Leprino Foods buying a dairy producer), while forward integration is moving forward in the value chain (Leprino Foods getting into the business of food distribution). Pose this question to students: At present, Leprino Foods buys milk from dairy companies, makes cheese in its facilities, and sells the cheese to large food distributors such as Sysco and Gordon Foods, who sell to pizza chains such as Pizza Hut and Domino’s. Does it make sense for Leprino Foods to expand by owing dairy companies or by getting into food distribution? Leprino Foods has to look at two metrics in making the decision: cost reduction and revenue enhancement. Synergies may help in cost containment and the ability to capture above normal profits helps on the income side. Slides 6-5 and 6-6 These slides will help you introduce the concepts of backward and forward integration using the pizza example from the previous slide. They also help in providing an overview of the economic logic of vertical integration. Ask students why Leprino might want to own a supplier or a distributor. Point out to students that Leprino has become so large that they now deal directly with some of the national pizza chains rather than going through distributors. In this regard, Leprino has engaged in a degree of vertical integration. Important Point: It is important to reiterate to students that vertical integration has to be driven by economic concerns. Going back to the logic of corporate-level strategy, the cost-benefit analysis of owning multiple businesses in the portfolio must be performed. ► Example: Amazon and the Publishing Industry The book publishing industry traditionally was characterized by a long value chain. The publisher contracted with authors to write books and entered into agreements with commercial printers (such as R.R. Donnelley and Quebecor) to print the books. Books were distributed to bookstores through wholesalers such as Ingram and Baker & Taylor. The major problem with this value chain was the amount of unsold books returned by booksellers. Publishers faced return rates as high as 30 percent, which added significantly to their costs. Seeing this inefficiency as an opening, Amazon changed the value chain. By going directly to publishers, Amazon was able to lower costs by cutting out wholesalers. More importantly, they placed orders with publishers after customers ordered from their website. This allowed Amazon to reduce drastically the returns to publishers (from 30% to 3%) and use this to bargain for better prices from them. Amazon backward integrated by bypassing the wholesaler and going directly to the publisher. (Laseter, Houston, Wright and Park. “Amazon your industry: Extracting Value from the Value Chain,” Strategy+ Business, First Quarter 2000) Class Activity Divide the class into groups of 4-5 students. Assign 2 groups to each industry and pick a company for each group. For example, in the personal care industry the two companies can be Procter and Gamble and Colgate-Palmolive. Have the group go to the company’s web page to the financials (in the section of the site marked “Investors.”) Using the formula given in the book, have them compute the level of vertical integration for their firm. If the level of vertical integration is markedly different for the two firms in an industry, have them discuss the merits and demerits of their company’s stance on this issue. Teaching Points • Use examples to help students clearly understand the concept of vertical integration. • Once the concept of vertical integration is clearly understood, explain the difference between backward and forward integration. • Encourage students to identify reasons why a firm would consider vertical integration. The Amazon example should help them get started. THE VALUE OF VERTICAL INTEGRATION A company’s decision whether or not to vertically integrate must be based on sound logic. The VRIO Framework is once again helpful in this regard. Slide 6-7 This slide reminds students that the VRIO Framework can be applied to a firm’s vertical integration strategy. A vertical integration strategy will only lead to competitive advantage if the value chain economies achieved meet the VRIO criteria. The two extremes in economic exchange are the market and integrated economic exchange (also called the hierarchy). In the market, the focal firm buys the product or service from outside players or sells its product to outside intermediaries. In integrated economic exchange, the firm performs these activities internally. Economic exchange should be conducted in a way that maximizes value for the focal firm. Integration makes strategic sense when the focal firm can capture more value than a market exchange provides. Slide 6-8 Use this slide to introduce the two forms of economic exchange and how the decision should be made on the value maximization criterion. Refer to the Leprino example to explain that when Leprino is buying milk from dairy farmers it is conducting that exchange in a market. If Leprino were to buy several large dairy farms, we would say that the exchange had been integrated into the hierarchy of Leprino. Once the overall value maximization logic of vertical integration is discussed, the focus can shift to specifics. Vertical integration can create value—decrease costs or increase revenues—in three situations: to reduce the threat of opportunism to leverage firm capabilities to remain flexible (possible with vertical integration under certain conditions) Vertical Integration and the Threat of Opportunism Discuss How Vertical Integration Can Create Value By Reducing The Threat Of Opportunism Opportunism is when a firm is unfairly exploited in an exchange. In other words, one of the two firms in an exchange holds up the other to the financial benefit of the first firm. The hold up can occur with regard to price, delivery terms, quality, etc. For the firm that is being held up, the exchange creates an economic loss. To avoid this, the firm can vertically integrate. By bringing the activity in-house, the firm controls it and therefore removes the possibility of opportunistic behavior causing economic losses. The decision to vertically integrate, though, has to be made by comparing the costs of vertical integration with its benefits. If the cost of opportunism is less than the cost of vertical integration, then the decision should be to continue with market exchange. At this point, students may still be vague about opportunism and why it is likely to occur in an exchange. Introducing the concept of transaction-specific investment using examples can help in clarifying this important concept. A transaction-specific investment is any investment in an exchange that has significantly more value in the current exchange than it does in alternative exchanges. The example of the oil refinery in the book is a good one to use because it describes a transaction-specific investment in visual form and examines its effect on value in numerical form. Once this example is gone through, the instructor can use a second example (given below) to reinforce the concept. If the pipeline laying company is the focal firm in the discussion, look at the issue from its perspective. It costs money to lay the pipeline but it brings value ($750,000) to the firm. But the value comes with a catch. The full value ($750,000) is only realized in the specific context of serving the oil refinery. Because of location issues, the value is diminished considerably (to around $10,000) if the context is changed. If the two firms agree on a 5-year contract on terms favorable to the oil pipeline company, then the transaction-specific investment makes strategic sense for the focal firm. But what happens after the initial contract runs out? That’s when opportunism (or its possibility) comes into play! In negotiating the second contract, who has the advantage? Obviously it is the oil refinery. They can bring down the price of the exchange so that they can profit. But the focal firm stands to lose because of this opportunism. It is likely, then that the focal firm will not be motivated to make this investment in the first place. Vertical integration is the recourse for the oil refinery because it takes care of the opportunism problem. ► Example: Bird’s Eye and the Frozen Foods Industry Birds Eye, the U.S. frozen foods maker, wanted to expand to the U.K. in the 1950s, attracted by the large market and the absence of a frozen food industry. One of the first products they sought to introduce in the U.K. was frozen vegetables. They contracted with farmers to grow vegetables for them. Their U.S. experience had taught them of the need to process the vegetables within 90 minutes of harvest. Processing vegetables after 90 minutes typically resulted in the product lacking freshness. Because the farmlands were on the outskirts of London, there were no processing plants in existence within the 90 minutes radius. Birds Eye contacted a number of processors and asked them to invest in a facility near the farmlands. Birds Eye could not find a single taker. Why would this happen? Investing near the farmlands is a transaction-specific investment. Its value would be great only in the context of serving Birds Eye and nobody else. Why would a processor make such a transaction-specific investment when the possibility of opportunistic behavior by Birds Eye is great? After the investment is made, Birds Eye could take advantage of this sunk cost by paying less to the processor. Birds Eye was forced to vertically integrate into owning processing plants because of this problem. (Collis and Grant, 1992. Birds Eye and the U.K. Frozen Food Industry, Harvard Business School Case) Vertical Integration and Firm Capabilities Discuss How Vertical Integration Can Create Value By Enabling A Firm To Exploit Its Valuable, Rare, and Costly-To-Imitate Resources And Capabilities Reducing the threat of opportunism can be seen as a defensive approach to vertical integration. Leveraging the focal firm’s capabilities, on the other hand, is a proactive approach to vertical integration. The logic here is simple: a firm should vertically integrate into those business activities where they possess valuable, rare, and costly-to-imitate resources and capabilities. This also means that a firm should not vertically integrate into activities where they do not have the resources to get a competitive advantage. ► Example: Installing Auditorium Seats A company that manufacturers seats for auditoriums and stadiums faced a difficult problem. The company manufactured seats to order and delivered the seats to firms that specialized in installation. The company won plaudits for the quality of its seats. However, they faced numerous complaints regarding poor installation. This motivated the company to consider the possibility of vertically integrating into the installation activity. When they analyzed the situation, they realized that none of the capabilities that were valuable in the manufacturing business (design, quality, etc.) created a competitive advantage in the installation business. Indeed, they had to develop new capabilities (managing a temporary, unskilled work force to generate efficiency, for example) to succeed in the installation business. The company decided against vertical integration! Important Point: What if the two motivations for vertical integration provide contrasting results? In other words, what if the opportunism argument points to vertical integration while the capabilities argument point to a market exchange? The instructor should help students confront this problem by using the Wal-Mart example in the text. In its 2014 10-K SEC filing, Hershey Foods indicated that Wal-Mart accounted for 25.5 percent of total sales in the year 2013 (sales were made to McLane Company, Wal-Mart’s primary distributor). Wal-Mart was responsible for 14 percent of Procter and Gamble’s 2013 revenues. It is very likely that similar percentages can be found for many of Wal-Mart’s leading suppliers. Wal-Mart clearly has tremendous bargaining power over these companies. Many of these companies have well-staffed offices in Bentonville, Arkansas, where Wal-Mart’s corporate headquarters is located. These are transaction-specific investments made by these companies to serve one customer, Wal-Mart. The opportunism minimization logic would indicate that these firms should forward integrate into retailing to reduce the possibility of losses due to Wal-Mart’s opportunistic behavior. But, do these firms have the resources to obtain a competitive advantage in retailing? Not likely. So, forward integration into retailing does not make sense from a capabilities viewpoint. Vertical Integration and Flexibility Discuss How Vertical Integration Can Create Value By Enabling A Firm To Retain Its Flexibility Flexibility pertains to the cost (and time) of changing the strategic and operational decisions of an organization. A flexible organization can change its strategic/operational choices quickly. In other words, such an organization can pivot on a dime! Less flexible organizations find this change difficult and costly. In general, vertical integration reduces a firm’s flexibility. Why? A vertically integrated organization has expanded its bureaucracy to include multiple activities. It has changed its structure, control system, and compensation practices to reflect this increased bureaucracy. Changing these takes time. Flexibility is not always a virtue. It is important to be flexible when the future is uncertain. In such situations, alternatives to vertical integration, particularly strategic alliances, may be better options. ► Example: Intel Capital Intel, the chipmaker, has a venture capital arm called Intel Capital. Its mission is to identify and invest in promising technology companies worldwide. Founded in 1991, Intel Capital has invested more than $11 billion in approximately 1,340 companies in over 55 countries by early 2014. These investments help Intel in two ways: it allows Intel to profit when these companies go public or are acquired by other companies. More importantly, though, these investments give Intel a first right of refusal on new technologies without the company having to vertically integrate into any of these when their future is uncertain. Intel capital’s website (www.intelcapital.com) Applying the Theories to the Management of Call Centers Call centers in the beginning (because of their novelty) required transaction-specific investments—physical infrastructure, communications technology, training, etc. Vertical integration made sense at that time. Changes in information technology, benefits of the learning curve in terms of employee training, and the ability to cater to multiple customers from one central location ushered in a huge growth in independent call center companies. This merchant market in call centers meant that firms did not have to vertically integrate into this activity. In the early stage, a firm could gain a competitive advantage by operating a call center. For example, Dell always resonated well with its customers because of the quality of its customer interaction through its call centers. But, today, almost every company seems to have one. It is no longer a means to competitive advantage. Besides, companies specializing in operating call centers developed a number of valuable and costly-to-imitate capabilities. It made sense for firms to outsource this function. As communication technology changes rapidly, firms face a lot of uncertainty in this regard. Investing in one technology to run a call center may put a firm at a disadvantage because its technology may quickly become obsolete. Outsourcing this function reduces the uncertainty for firms. ► Example: Call Centers in India India is a leading player in the call center industry. Companies such as Chrysler, British Telecom, Citigroup, and American Express all do business with Indian call center companies. GE has gone a step further. It operates call centers (serving clients) in India. It provides a variety of services for its clients: transaction processing, help desks, IT-related queries from U.S. clients, accounting services, etc. Why does India dominate in this industry? A key reason is that manpower accounts for 55-60 percent of the cost of running a call center. In India, manpower (particularly tech-savy, English speaking labor) is available at a fraction of the cost overseas. In addition, the Indian government provides various incentives for companies to run call centers. Outsource India website (www.outsource2India.com) Important Point: It is important for the instructor to reiterate that the three arguments related to the vertical integration decision may conflict with each other and confuse decision-making. In other words, the opportunism argument may point to vertical integration, while the capabilities and the flexibility arguments may point to de-integration. In such cases, the firm has to look at the trade-offs involved and use cost versus benefits to make the decision. This is also a good occasion to looks at the ethics of outsourcing discussed in the ‘Ethics and Strategy” box in the text. Slide 6-9 Use this slide to take students through the three value considerations in vertical integration. Emphasize that vertical integration can create value because of any of these issues. A single vertical integration move could create value for all three reasons. Teaching Points • Ensure that students understand what opportunism is. Use examples to explain this concept. • Reiterate to students that leveraging capabilities is a key issue in vertical integration. • Point out to students that flexibility is important in today’s business world and that it may be more vital in some industries than in others. • At the end of the discussion of this section, take them through a summary of the three main issues in vertical integration decisions. • Ask students for examples of vertical integration they have read about in the business press and use the concepts in this chapter to examine the economic logic of these moves. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND SUSTAINED COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE Describe Conditions Under Which Vertical Integration May Be Rare and Costly To Imitate This is a good time to go back to the VRIO Framework and establish its connection with vertical integration. In order for vertical integration to be a source of sustained competitive advantage, it must not only be valuable but also rare and costly to imitate, and the firm must be organized to implement this strategy. The Rarity of Vertical Integration Slide 6-10 Use this slide to look at integration vs. non-integration from a rarity viewpoint. The value chain economies achieved by a firm through vertical integration may be rare even if many competitors have vertically integrated. Toyota is a good example of a company that could have vertically integrated many of its suppliers. However, it has chosen to establish relationships with suppliers that provide Toyota with many of the value chain economies that competitors can only get through actually owning suppliers. The point being that the substance or function of a vertical integration strategy rather than the form of the strategy is what really matters in terms of rarity. Rarity in vertical integration may be because of one of two things: a firm is rare in being able to operate its vertically integrated units very efficiently. Or, it could the one firm in the industry that is not vertically integrated while all others are. A firm may be able to create value (more than others in the industry) through vertical integration because of three reasons: rare transaction-specific investments need to be made that prompts a firm to vertically integrate to leverage specific capabilities that would give it a competitive advantage ability to resolve uncertainty ahead of others in the industry In the first case, the firm has developed a special technology or a new approach to doing business, while others in the industry have not. Because this special technology/approach to doing business requires transaction-specific investment, the firm is vertically integrated, while others in the industry are non-integrated. In the second case, the firm has a valuable capability that allows it to benefit from vertical integration. Others do not have this capability and hence are not vertically integrated. In the third reason, the firm has the ability to resolve the uncertainty that all firms in the industry face. While others may be non-integrated because of this uncertainty, the focal firm may be vertically integrated. In all the cases above, the focal firm decides to vertically integrate while others in the industry do not. But, there may also be a case where others are vertically integrated while the focal firm benefits from being de-integrated. It creates value for itself by being able to manage these market economic exchanges efficiently. The Imitability of Vertical Integration The ability to create value through vertical integration (or by de-integration) may not be rare for too long if it can be imitated. Imitation can be through direct duplication or through substitution. Direct duplication of a firm’s vertical integration involves two things: copying the form and copying the value creation potential. While copying the form may not be costly, copying the value creation potential may be costly because of factors such as historical uniqueness, causal ambiguity, and social complexity. Imitation may also be difficult if there are not very many firms to acquire in order to vertically integrate (the small numbers problem) or where entry barriers are quite high. Slide 6-11 Use this slide to identify the factors involved in direct duplication of a firm’s vertical integration strategy. Remind students that the cost of duplicating the actual value chain economies is a more important consideration than the cost of simply duplicating the form. An imitator may choose not to directly duplicate the value creation potential of another firm’s vertical integration strategy. Instead, it may choose substitute modes that give it the same benefit. Internal development and strategic alliances are two important substitute modes. Slide 6-12 Remind students that the logic of vertical integration is to choose the most efficient form of exchange. Firms can choose from the market (no vertical integration), an acquisition (fully integrated), internal development (fully integrated), or a strategic alliance (partial vertical integration). Of course, the specific conditions of any given situation dictate which form is most appropriate. Teaching Points • Reiterate the importance of using the VRIO Framework to evaluate the strategy of vertical integration. • Encourage students to examine the rarity and imitability questions relative to the value chain economies achieved by firms rather than relative to the form of the exchange per se. • Emphasize that in analyzing a firm’s vertical integration strategy, one would want to ask the question: Can competitors imitate the value chain economies of the firm through alternate vertical integration strategies? ORGANIZING TO IMPLEMENT VERTICAL INTEGRATION Describe How The Functional Organization Structure, Management Controls, and Compensation Policies Are Used To Implement Vertical Integration Organizing to implement a vertical integration strategy is the last step, the “O” in the VRIO Framework that looks at how vertical integration can create a sustained competitive advantage. A firm must have the appropriate infrastructure—organizational structure, management controls, and compensation policies to successfully implement a vertical integration strategy. Organizational Structure and Implementing Vertical Integration The functional or U-form structure allows the firm to implement a strategy of vertical integration. Slide 6-13 Explain that the CEO’s responsibilities usually become much more complex as a result of vertical integration. The functions of the new business must be integrated with the functions of the existing business. Point out that the achievement of the desired value chain economies depends on the ability of the CEO and other managers to integrate the functions of the new and existing businesses. As the slide indicates, the function brought within the firm’s boundaries because of vertical integration is “folded in” to the same function already existing in the organization. For example, if a company manufacturing a consumer product vertically integrates into manufacturing its packaging products, the packaging product’s manufacturing function is folded in with the consumer product’s manufacturing function. The CEO in this vertically integrated U-form has the same responsibilities as identified in Chapter 4: strategy formulation and strategy implementation. An added dimension in a vertically integrated firm is to continually assess the value creation potential of vertical integration. In addition, the CEO has also to resolve conflicts arising among the various functions. Since each function in a U-form organization functions in a silo, their perspective is likely to be very narrow. This could lead to conflicts among functions. This is a good time for the instructor to point out to students that, depending on their major, they are likely to view an organization from different perspectives. Accountants typically are obsessive about cost control, while marketers and R&D people may not have the same attention to cost control. Sales and manufacturing always seem to have conflicts – manufacturing blaming sales for poor sales forecasts that leaves a lot of unsold goods in inventory and so on. It is important for the instructor to go back to Slide 6-13 and point out that the CEO’s job involves facilitating cooperation among functions and minimizing the ill effects of conflicts among these functions. Management Controls and Implementing Vertical Integration As indicated above, vertical integration strategies typically require that one business be integrated with an existing business (in the case of acquisition). Such integration presents some potentially challenging management issues. These issues revolve around aligning the interests of managers, new and existing, with the interests of the newly combined firm. Slide 6-14 This slide provides some context for a discussion of management controls. Emphasize that the need for management controls arises because the achievement of value chain economies depends on managers behaving in certain ways. Managers from the new business and managers from the existing business must be able to get along with each other. Managers usually need to be given incentives to adopt a long-term focus so that the integrated firm can achieve value chain economies over the long run. Once the U-form structure’s importance in implementing a vertical integration strategy is established, the discussion should turn to management control processes. Two key ones need to be addressed here: budgets management committees Budgets help in the control process by identifying the metrics by which performance is to be measured. A vertically integrated firm may develop budgets in a variety of areas: sales, costs, etc. Typically budgets are tied into the compensation process, in that managers may receive bonuses depending on how close they are to their budget. While budgets help in the control process, they may have serious downsides. Primary among them is the fact that budgets are likely to promote short-term behavior (controlling expenses today to meet budget but not preparing for the future) at the cost of long-term actions. Involving managers in the budgeting process and using qualitative measures in addition to quantitative ones can help in this regard. Internal management committees that meet periodically also help in the control process. Two common ones (though they may go by different names in organizations) are: the executive committee the operations committee The difference between the two types of committees is essentially in their focus: the executive committee tends to focus on short-term firm performance, while the operations committee has a long-term view of firm performance. Both committees are staffed by the CEO and key functional area managers. They meet regularly (typically, weekly for the executive committee and monthly for the operations committee) to identify problems and come up with solutions. Such committees also help in reducing the conflicts among departments. Slide 6-15 Explain that strategic budgets are used to encourage investment that will benefit the firm in the long run. For example, a strategic budget may set aside capital to be invested in a new plant or for the hiring of new R&D engineers. The purpose of a strategic budget is to separate strategic investment from normal operating spending. This is one way to remove the incentive for managers to curtail strategic investment so that they can meet short-term financial targets. A strategic budget is concerned with the inputs, i.e. spending on strategic initiatives, and outputs, i.e. performance of the investment. Operational budgets cover normal operations. Point out that board committees may also play a role in helping to focus management attention on the issues necessary to achieve the desired value chain economies. Compensation in Implementing Vertical Integration Strategies Compensation is the third piece of the “Organizing” puzzle. As such it complements both structure and control systems and helps guide behavior toward desired ends. The three explanations for vertical integration (opportunism, capabilities, and flexibility) have important compensation implications. The instructor should structure this discussion around this idea. Very often employees make firm-specific investments of their own. They expend energy cultivating skills valuable to the organization, imbibe the organizational culture and establish contacts within and outside the firm. Such investments are valuable only in the context of the firm, in that, once the employee leaves the firm, much of the investment declines in value. Employees know that if they make such firm-specific investments, they are vulnerable because the firm can treat them badly without worrying that the employee will seek employment elsewhere. So how should an organization encourage its employees to invest in firm-specific skills in light of this possibility? They should do it by providing incentives as part of their compensation. While the previous paragraph talked about providing incentives for individuals to invest in firm-specific skills, there is also the fact that groups of employees make firm-specific investments. Very often, it is the tacit collective knowledge of these groups of employees that give the firm valuable costly-to-imitate capabilities. The firm’s compensation policy must encourage such collective firm-specific investment. Compensation practices must also take into account the importance of flexibility. Employees must be encouraged to engage in activities that allow the firm to be flexible in order to take advantage of opportunities. Table 6.1 in the text portrays the various aspects of compensation aligned with the three explanations for vertical integration. The instructor should use this table to tie the compensation challenges in vertical integration with specific alternatives. It is important to reiterate that the opportunism explanation calls for individual rewards – salary, cash bonus for individual performance, and stock grants for individual performance – while the capabilities explanation suggests group-based rewards. The flexibility explanation suggests covering the downside risk for employees but provide stock grants for upside potential. Slide 6-16 This slide depicts how various compensation alternatives can be used in an effort to achieve value chain economies by aligning the interests of managers with the interests of the organization. Point out that how people are compensated can change their incentives to work together with others, to focus on the long-term versus the short-term, etc. Teaching Points • Explain that organization is a vital part of a successful vertical integration strategy. • Reiterate the importance of the three explanations for vertical integration by tying them to the discussion on organization. • Use Table 6.1 to summarize this section by taking students through the various compensation options as they relate to the three explanations for vertical integration. SUMMARY OF VERTICAL INTEGRATION It is a good idea to summarize the discussion on vertical integration by stating this: historically, the default was vertical integration. That is, firms were vertically integrated into performing multiple value chain activities unless there were compelling reasons not to do so. Gigantic oil companies such as Standard Oil and Exxon (now ExxonMobil) were almost fully vertically integrated. Today, the pendulum has shifted to the opposite side. Firms are typically non-integrated unless there is a compelling reason to be vertically integrated. Reiterating the conditions under which vertical integration makes sense is important at this point. Reducing/preventing opportunism, leveraging capabilities, and increasing flexibility are good reasons under certain conditions for vertical integration. Slide 6-17 Use this slide to remind students that vertical integration makes sense under certain conditions. Call attention to the fact that a vertical integration strategy is a matter of deciding which form of economic exchange is the most efficient. Point out that a vertical integration strategy that is not valuable, rare, and costly-to-imitate is unlikely to generate competitive advantage. The instructor should close this chapter by pointing the important caveat with respect to vertical integration—it is costly and so it is necessary to weigh the costs and benefits before making the decision. Slide 6-18 Remind students that vertical integration is an element of corporate level strategy. As such, a vertical integration strategy should create value according to the logic of corporate level strategy. Use this slide to reiterate that ownership comes with a price and so caution must be applied in making the decision to vertically integrate. Instructor Manual for Strategic Management and Competitive Advantage Concepts and Cases Jay B. Berney, William S. Hesterly 9781292060088, 9781292258041
Close