Preview (15 of 48 pages)

Answers to Textbook Questions and Problems CHAPTER 7 Unemployment and the Labor Market Questions for Review 1. The rates of job separation and job finding determine the natural rate of unemployment. The rate of job separation is the fraction of people who lose their job each month. The higher the rate of job separation, the higher the natural rate of unemployment. The rate of job finding is the fraction of unemployed people who find a job each month. The higher the rate of job finding, the lower the natural rate of unemployment. 2. Frictional unemployment is the unemployment caused by the time it takes to match workers and jobs. Finding an appropriate job takes time because the flow of information about job candidates and job vacancies is not instantaneous. Because different jobs require different skills and pay different wages, unemployed workers may not accept the first job offer they receive. In contrast, structural unemployment is the unemployment resulting from wage rigidity and job rationing. These workers are unemployed not because they are actively searching for a job that best suits their skills (as in the case of frictional unemployment), but because at the prevailing real wage the quantity of labor supplied exceeds the quantity of labor demanded. If the wage does not adjust to clear the labor market, then these workers must wait for jobs to become available. Structural unemployment thus arises because firms fail to reduce wages despite an excess supply of labor. 3. The real wage may remain above the level that equilibrates labor supply and labor demand because of minimum wage laws, the monopoly power of unions, and efficiency wages. Minimum-wage laws cause wage rigidity when they prevent wages from falling to equilibrium levels. Although most workers are paid a wage above the minimum level, for some workers, especially the unskilled and inexperienced, the minimum wage raises their wage above the equilibrium level. It therefore reduces the quantity of their labor that firms demand, and creates an excess supply of workers, which increases unemployment. The monopoly power of unions causes wage rigidity because the wages of unionized workers are determined not by the equilibrium of supply and demand but by collective bargaining between union leaders and firm management. The wage agreement often raises the wage above the equilibrium level and allows the firm to decide how many workers to employ. These high wages cause firms to hire fewer workers than at the market-clearing wage, so structural unemployment increases. Efficiency-wage theories suggest that high wages make workers more productive. The influence of wages on worker efficiency may explain why firms do not cut wages despite an excess supply of labor. Even though a wage reduction decreases the firm’s wage bill, it may also lower worker productivity and therefore the firm’s profits. 4. Depending on how one looks at the data, most unemployment can appear to be either short term or long term. Most spells of unemployment are short; that is, most of those who became unemployed find jobs quickly. On the other hand, most weeks of unemployment are attributable to the small number of long-term unemployed. By definition, the long-term unemployed do not find jobs quickly, so they appear on unemployment rolls for many weeks or months. 5. Europeans work fewer hours than Americans. One explanation is that the higher income tax rates in Europe reduce the incentive to work. A second explanation is a larger underground economy in Europe as a result of more people attempting to evade the high tax rates. A third explanation is the greater importance of unions in Europe and their ability to bargain for reduced work hours. A final explanation is based on preferences, whereby Europeans value leisure more than Americans do, and therefore elect to work fewer hours. Problems and Applications 1. a. In the example that follows, we assume that during the school year you look for a part-time job, and that, on average, it takes 2 weeks to find one. We also assume that the typical job lasts 1 semester, or 12 weeks. b. If it takes 2 weeks to find a job, then the rate of job finding in weeks is f = (1 job/2 weeks) = 0.5 jobs/week. If the job lasts for 12 weeks, then the rate of job separation in weeks is s = (1 job/12 weeks) = 0.083 jobs/week. c. From the text, we know that the formula for the natural rate of unemployment is (U/L) = [s/(s + f )], where U is the number of people unemployed, and L is the number of people in the labor force. Plugging in the values for f and s that were calculated in part (b), we find (U/L) = [0.083/(0.083 + 0.5)] = 0.14. Thus, if on average it takes 2 weeks to find a job that lasts 12 weeks, the natural rate of unemployment for this population of college students seeking part-time employment is 14 percent. 2. Call the number of residents of the dorm who are involved I, the number who are uninvolved U, and the total number of students T = I + U. In steady state the total number of involved students is constant. For this to happen we need the number of newly uninvolved students, (0.10)I, to be equal to the number of students who just became involved, (0.05)U. Following a few substitutions: (0.05)U = (0.10)I = (0.10)(T – U), so U 0.10 = T 0.10 + 0.05 = . We find that two-thirds of the students are uninvolved. 3. To show that the unemployment rate evolves over time to the steady-state rate, let’s begin by defining how the number of people unemployed changes over time. The change in the number of unemployed equals the number of people losing jobs (sE) minus the number finding jobs (fU). In equation form, we can express this as: Ut + 1 – Ut = ΔUt + 1 = sEt – fUt. Recall from the text that L = Et + Ut, or Et = L – Ut, where L is the total labor force (we will assume that L is constant). Substituting for Et in the above equation, we find ΔUt + 1 = s(L – Ut) – fUt. Dividing by L, we get an expression for the change in the unemployment rate from t to t + 1: ΔUt + 1/L = (Ut + 1/L) – (Ut/L) = Δ[U/L]t + 1 = s(1 – Ut/L) – fUt/L. Rearranging terms on the right side of the equation above, we end up with line 1 below. Now take line 1 below, multiply the right side by (s + f)/(s + f) and rearrange terms to end up with line 2 below: Δ[U/L]t + 1 = s – (s + f)Ut/L = (s + f)[s/(s + f) – Ut/L]. The first point to note about this equation is that in steady state, when the unemployment rate equals its natural rate, the left-hand side of this expression equals zero. This tells us that, as we found in the text, the natural rate of unemployment (U/L)n equals s/(s + f). We can now rewrite the above expression, substituting (U/L)n for s/(s + f), to get an equation that is easier to interpret: Δ[U/L]t + 1 = (s + f)[(U/L)n – Ut/L]. This expression shows the following: • If Ut/L > (U/L)n (that is, the unemployment rate is above its natural rate), then Δ[U/L]t + 1 is negative: the unemployment rate falls. • If Ut/L < (U/L)n (that is, the unemployment rate is below its natural rate), then Δ[U/L]t + 1 is positive: the unemployment rate rises. This process continues until the unemployment rate U/L reaches the steady-state rate (U/L)n. 4. Consider the formula for the natural rate of unemployment, U s = L s+ f If the new law lowers the chance of separation s, but has no effect on the rate of job finding f, then the natural rate of unemployment falls. For several reasons, however, the new law might tend to reduce f. First, raising the cost of firing might make firms more careful about hiring workers, since firms have a harder time firing workers who turn out to be a poor match. Second, if job searchers think that the new legislation will lead them to spend a longer period of time on a particular job, then they might weigh more carefully whether or not to take that job. If the reduction in f is large enough, then the new policy may even increase the natural rate of unemployment. 5. a. The demand for labor is determined by the amount of labor that a profit-maximizing firm wants to hire at a given real wage. The profit-maximizing condition is that the firm hire labor until the marginal product of labor equals the real wage, W MPL= P The marginal product of labor is found by differentiating the production function with respect to labor (see Chapter 3 for more discussion), dY MPL= dL d(5K1/3L2/3) = dL = K1/3L-1/3 In order to solve for labor demand, we set the MPL equal to the real wage and solve for L: 10 K1/3L-1/3 =W 3 P -3 1,000 W L= K 27 Ł Pł Notice that this expression has the intuitively desirable feature that increases in the real wage reduce the demand for labor. b. We assume that the 27,000 units of capital and the 1,000 units of labor are supplied inelastically (i.e., they will work at any price). In this case we know that all 1,000 units of labor and 27,000 units of capital will be used in equilibrium, so we can substitute these values into the above labor W demand function and solve for . P -3 1,000 W 1,000 = (27,000) 27 Ł Pł W =10. P In equilibrium, employment will be 1,000, and multiplying this by 10 we find that the workers earn 10,000 units of output. The total output is given by the production function: = 5 = 5 27,000 1,000 = 15,000. Notice that workers get two-thirds of output, which is consistent with what we know about the Cobb–Douglas production function from Chapter 3. c. The real wage is now equal to 11 (10% above the equilibrium level of 10). Firms will use their labor demand function to decide how many workers to hire at the given real wage of 11 and capital stock of 27,000: -3 L=27,000 11( ) L= 751. So 751 workers will be hired for a total compensation of 8,261 units of output. To find the new level of output, plug the new value for labor and the value for capital into the production function and you will find Y = 12,393. d. The policy redistributes output from the 249 workers who become involuntarily unemployed to the 751 workers who get paid more than before. The lucky workers benefit less than the losers lose as the total compensation to the working class falls from 10,000 to 8,261 units of output. e. This problem does focus on the analysis of two effects of the minimum-wage laws: they raise the wage for some workers while downward-sloping labor demand reduces the total number of jobs. Note, however, that if labor demand is less elastic than in this example, then the loss of employment may be smaller, and the change in worker income might be positive. 6. a. The labor demand curve is given by the marginal product of labor schedule faced by firms. If a country experiences a reduction in productivity, then the labor demand curve shifts to the left as in Figure 7-1. If labor becomes less productive, then at any given real wage, firms demand less labor. b. If the labor market is always in equilibrium, then, assuming a fixed labor supply, an adverse productivity shock causes a decrease in the real wage but has no effect on employment or unemployment, as in Figure 7-2. c. If unions constrain real wages to remain unaltered, then as illustrated in Figure 7-3, employment This example shows that the effect of a productivity shock on an economy depends on the role of unions and the response of collective bargaining to such a change. 7. a. If workers are free to move between sectors, then the wage in each sector will be equal. If the wages were not equal then workers would have an incentive to move to the sector with the higher wage and this would cause the higher wage to fall, and the lower wage to rise until they were equal. b. Since there are 100 workers in total, LS = 100 – LM. We can substitute this expression into the labor demand for services equation, and call the wage w since it is the same in both sectors: LS = 100 – LM = 100 – 4w LM = 4w. Now set this equal to the labor demand for manufacturing equation and solve for w: 4w = 200 – 6w w = $20. Substitute the wage into the two labor demand equations to find LM is 80 and LS is 20. c. If the wage in manufacturing is equal to $25 then LM is equal to 50. d. There are now 50 workers employed in the service sector and the wage wS is equal to $12.50. e. The wage in manufacturing will remain at $25 and employment will remain at 50. If the reservation wage for the service sector is $15 then employment in the service sector will be 40. Therefore, 10 people are unemployed and the unemployment rate is 10 percent. 8. Real wages have risen over time in both the United States and Europe, increasing the reward for working (the substitution effect) but also making people richer, so they want to “buy” more leisure (the income effect). If the income effect dominates, then people want to work less as real wages go up. This could explain the European experience, in which hours worked per employed person have fallen over time. If the income and substitution effects approximately cancel, then this could explain the U.S. experience, in which hours worked per person have stayed about constant. Economists do not have good theories for why tastes might differ, so they disagree on whether it is reasonable to think that Europeans have a larger income effect than do Americans. 9. The vacant office space problem is similar to the unemployment problem; we can apply the same concepts we used in analyzing unemployed labor to analyze why vacant office space exists. There is a rate of office separation: firms that occupy offices leave, either to move to different offices or because they go out of business. There is a rate of office finding: firms that need office space (either to start up or expand) find empty offices. It takes time to match firms with available space. Different types of firms require spaces with different attributes depending on what their specific needs are. Also, because demand for different goods fluctuates, there are “sectoral shifts”—changes in the composition of demand among industries and regions that affect the profitability and office needs of different firms. IN THIS CHAPTER, YOU WILL LEARN: …about the natural rate of unemployment: ▪ what it means ▪ what causes it ▪ understanding its behavior in the real world 1 Natural rate of unemployment ▪ Natural rate of unemployment: The average rate of unemployment around which the economy fluctuates. ▪ In a recession, the actual unemployment rate rises above the natural rate. ▪ In a boom, the actual unemployment rate falls below the natural rate. A first model of the natural rate Notation: L = # of workers in labor force E = # of employed workers U = # of unemployed U/L = unemployment rate Assumptions: 1. L is exogenously fixed. 2. During any given month, s = rate of job separations, fraction of employed workers that become separated from their jobs f = rate of job finding, fraction of unemployed workers that find jobs s and f are exogenous The transitions between employment and unemployment Employed Unemployed f ×U The steady state condition ▪ Definition: the labor market is in steady state, or long-run equilibrium, if the unemployment rate is constant. ▪ The steady-state condition is: s ×E = f ×U # of employed people who # of unemployed lose or leave people who find their jobs jobs Finding the “equilibrium” U-rate f ×U = s ×E = s ×(L – U ) = s ×L – s ×U Solve for U/L: U s = L s +f (f + s) × U = s × L so, Example: ▪ Each month, ▪ 1% of employed workers lose their jobs (s = 0.01) ▪ 19% of unemployed workers find jobs (f = 0.19) ▪ Find the natural rate of unemployment: U s 0 01. = = = 0 05. , or 5% L s f+ 0 01. + 0 19. Policy implication ▪ A policy will reduce the natural rate of unemployment only if it lowers s or increases f. Why is there unemployment? ▪ If job finding were instantaneous (f = 1), then all spells of unemployment would be brief, and the natural rate would be near zero. ▪ There are two reasons why f < 1: 1. job search 2. wage rigidity Job search & frictional unemployment ▪ frictional unemployment: caused by the time it takes workers to search for a job ▪ occurs even when wages are flexible and there are enough jobs to go around ▪ occurs because ▪ workers have different abilities, preferences ▪jobs have different skill requirements ▪geographic mobility of workers not instantaneous ▪flow of information about vacancies and job candidates is imperfect Sectoral shifts ▪ def: Changes in the composition of demand among industries or regions. ▪ example: Technological change more jobs repairing computers, fewer jobs repairing typewriters ▪ example: A new international trade agreement labor demand increases in export sectors, decreases in import-competing sectors ▪ These scenarios result in frictional unemployment CASE STUDY: Structural change over the long run Agriculture Manufacturing 1960 Other industry 2012 Services More examples of sectoral shifts ▪ Industrial revolution (1800s): agriculture declines, manufacturing soars ▪ Energy crisis (1970s): demand shifts from larger cars to smaller ones ▪ Health care spending as % of GDP: 1960: 5.2 2000: 13.8 1980: 9.1 2010: 17.9 In our dynamic economy, smaller sectoral shifts occur frequently, contributing to frictional unemployment. Public policy and job search Govt programs affecting unemployment include: ▪ Govt employment agencies disseminate info about job openings to better match workers & jobs. ▪ Public job training programs help workers displaced from declining industries get skills needed for jobs in growing industries. Unemployment insurance (UI) ▪ UI pays part of a worker’s former wages for a limited time after the worker loses his/her job. ▪ UI increases frictional unemployment, because it reduces ▪ the opportunity cost of being unemployed ▪ the urgency of finding work ▪ f ▪ Studies: The longer a worker is eligible for UI, the longer the average spell of unemployment. Benefits of UI ▪ By allowing workers more time to search, UI may lead to better matches between jobs and workers, which would lead to greater productivity and higher incomes. Why is there unemployment? U s The natural rate of unemployment: = L s f+ ▪ Two reasons why f < 1: DONE ✓1. job search Next ➔2. wage rigidity Unemployment from real wage rigidity If real wage is stuck above its eq’m level, there aren’t enough jobs to go around. Unemployment from real wage rigidity If real wage is stuck above its eq’m level, there aren’t enough jobs to go around. Then, firms must ration the scarce jobs among workers. Structural unemployment: The unemployment resulting from real wage rigidity and job rationing. Reasons for wage rigidity 1. Minimum-wage laws 2. Labor unions 3. Efficiency wages 1. Minimum-wage laws ▪ The min. wage may exceed the eq’m wage of unskilled workers, especially teenagers. ▪ Studies: a 10% increase in min. wage reduces teen employment by 1–3% ▪ But, the min. wage cannot explain the majority of the natural rate of unemployment, as most workers’ wages are well above the min. wage. 2. Labor unions ▪ Unions exercise monopoly power to secure higher wages for their members. ▪ When the union wage exceeds the eq’m wage, unemployment results. ▪ Insiders: Employed union workers whose interest is to keep wages high. ▪ Outsiders: Unemployed non-union workers who prefer eq’m wages, so there would be enough jobs for them. 3. Efficiency wages ▪ Theories in which higher wages increase worker productivity by: ▪ attracting higher quality job applicants ▪ increasing worker effort, reducing “shirking” ▪ reducing turnover, which is costly to firms ▪ improving health of workers (in developing countries) ▪ Firms willingly pay above-equilibrium wages to raise productivity. ▪ Result: structural unemployment. EXPLAINING THE TREND: Demographics ▪ 1970s: The Baby Boomers were young. Young workers change jobs more frequently (high value of s). ▪ Late 1980s through today: Baby Boomers aged. Middle-aged workers change jobs less often (low s). CHAPTER 7 Unemployment and the Labor Market Why unemployment rose in Europe but not the U.S. Shock Technological progress has shifted labor demand from unskilled to skilled workers in recent decades. Effect in United States An increase in the “skill premium” – the wage gap between skilled and unskilled workers. Effect in Europe Higher unemployment, due to generous govt benefits for unemployed workers and strong union presence. CHAPTER 7 Unemployment and the Labor Market 1. The natural rate of unemployment ▪definition: the long-run average or “steady state” rate of unemployment ▪depends on the rates of job separation and job finding 2. Frictional unemployment ▪due to the time it takes to match workers with jobs ▪may be increased by unemployment insurance 3. Structural unemployment ▪results from wage rigidity: the real wage remains above the equilibrium level ▪caused by: minimum wage, unions, efficiency wages 4. Duration of unemployment ▪most spells are short term ▪but most weeks of unemployment are attributable to a small number of long-term unemployed persons 5. Behavior of the natural rate in the U.S. ▪rose from 1960 to early 1980s, then fell ▪possible explanations: trends in real minimum wage, union membership, prevalence of sectoral shifts, and aging of the Baby Boomers 6. European unemployment ▪has risen sharply since 1970 ▪probably due to generous unemployment benefits, strong union presence, and a technology-driven shift in demand away from unskilled workers Solution Manual for Macroeconomics Gregory N. Mankiw 9781464182891, 9781319106058

Document Details

Related Documents

person
Emma Thompson View profile
Close

Send listing report

highlight_off

You already reported this listing

The report is private and won't be shared with the owner

rotate_right
Close
rotate_right
Close

Send Message

image
Close

My favorites

image
Close

Application Form

image
Notifications visibility rotate_right Clear all Close close
image
image
arrow_left
arrow_right